Introduction to Behavioral Finance – Part 2: Limits of Arbitrage (2024)

In the first part of our series, “Introduction to Behavioral Finance – Part 1: Behavioral Bias,” we explored several market anomalies, and the first required condition for the real-life implementability of many quantitative strategies: the existence of human behavioral biases. In Part 2 of our series, we consider a related question: given that certain behavioral biases can affect investors, how can it be that their effects persist in markets so we can take advantage of them? This would seem to contravene the notion of efficient markets, and leads to the second required condition for implementing a tradable strategy: limits of arbitrage.

John Maynard Keynes was a shrewd observer of financial markets, and a successful investor in his own right. His investing success, however, was uneven, and at one point he was reportedly wiped out while speculating on leveraged currencies. This perhaps led him to make the famous statement (debated!):

Markets can remain irrational a lot longer than you and I can remain solvent.

Clearly, there were limits to Keynes’s ability to realize arbitrage profits, and these limits generally form the basis of Part 2 of our Introduction to Behavioral Finance series.

The Efficient Market Hypothesis

The Efficient Market Hypothesis (the “EMH”), pioneeredby Eugene Fama, states that there are varying forms of market efficiency. Of particular interest is semi-strong market efficiency, which claims that markets prices reflect all publicly available information about securities. When mispricings occur in markets, they should be immediately eliminated by arbitrageurs, who exploit these opportunities for a profit. Therefore, in the EMH view, prices should always reflect fundamental value.

In Part 1, we discussed the Value and Momentum anomalies, and how they were related to certain behavioral biases. But, as discussed, in light of the EMH, these should be quickly arbitraged away. Yet they are not. Why not?

The reason these anomalies can exist is that, as Keynes discovered, there are limits to the arbitrage process, which can be constrained in various ways. These limits, when they can be identified, can provide us an opportunity to trade against our pernicious behavioral biases.

Limits of arbitrage

Let’s quickly review the concept of arbitrage. The textbook definition of “arbitrage” involves a costless investment that generates riskless profits, by taking advantage of mispricings across different instruments representing the same security. Arbitrage is critical to the maintenance of efficient markets, since it is through the arbitrage process that fundamental values are kept aligned with market prices. In practice, arbitrage entails costs as well as the assumption of risk, and for these reasons, there are limits to the effectiveness of arbitrage in eliminating certain security mispricings. There is ample evidence for such limits to arbitrage.

Many of these limits are explored in a ground-breaking 1997 paper called, appropriately, “The Limits of Arbitrage,” (which can be found here: http://ms.mcmaster.ca/~grasselli/ShleiferVishny97.pdf) by Shleifer and Vishny. Below we consider a few limits to arbitrage, and finally, some that may apply to our situation as value investors in the stock market.

Fundamental Risk. Arbitrageurs may identify a mispricing of a security that does not have a close substitute that enables riskless arbitrage. If a piece of bad news affects the substitute security involved in hedging, the arbitrageur may be subject to unanticipated losses.

A good example here is a pairs trading strategy, which employs two nearly identical securities in the arbitrage process. Say co*ke and Pepsi traditionally trade at a similar valuation, a P/E of 10, yet for some reason, co*ke has become very expensive at 20X earnings, while Pepsi remains at a 10X multiple. The arbitrageur would go long Pepsi and short co*ke. When the multiples converge to historical equality, at some point in the future, the arbitrageur would realize gains. But what if Pepsi declined to a 5X multiple and co*ke increased to a 30X multiple for the next 5 years? The arbitrageur is exposed to the fundamental risks of each security.

Noise Trader Risk. Noise traders limit arbitrage. Once a position is taken, noise traders may drive prices farther from fundamental value, and the arbitrageur may be forced to invest additional capital, which may not be available, forcing an early liquidation of the position.

Complicating Noise Trader Risk is the structure of many arbitrage markets. Shleifer and Vishny point out that “millions of little traders” don’t have access to the same information that professional, specialized arbitrageurs do. These professional arbitrageurs, who thus do the bulk of the market’s arbitrage work, will go out and raise capital from third parties to ply their trade. If an arbitrage spread widens, however, these third parties may disrupt the arbitrage process by pulling their capital, just when it is most needed to keep an arbitrage trade on.

A good example is the 2011 bankruptcy of MF Global. MF Global was fundamentally pursuing an arbitrage trade. The firm bought discounted European bonds (that were guaranteed by the European Stability Facility), and then used them as collateral for new loans, which they used to buy yet more bonds. So the bonds were guaranteed, and MF Global only had to repay the loans when the bonds matured at par – in an amount greater than what was owed. It was the perfect arbitrage trade! The ultimate outcome, however, clearly demonstrates the limits to arbitrage: noisy traders pushed bond spreads wider, and MF Global got hit with a margin call that bankrupted the firm.

Implementation Costs. Short selling is often used in the arbitrage process, although it can be expensive due to the “short rebate,” representing the costs to borrow the stock to be sold short. In some cases, such borrowing costs may exceed potential profits. If short rebate fees are 10% or 20%, then arbitrage profits must exceed these costs to achieve profitability. That’s a tall order.

Performance Requirements/Agency Costs. Another short-circuit to the arbitrage process relates to limits imposed by variations in performance, and how they affect money manager incentives. Consider the pressures produced by “tracking error,” or the tendency of returns to deviate from a benchmark.

Say you have a job investing the pensions of 100,000 firemen. You have a choice of investment strategies. You can invest in:

  • Strategy A: A strategy that you know (by some magical means) will beat the market by 1% per year over 25 years. You also know that you will never underperform the index by more than 1% in a given year; or
  • Strategy B:An arbitrage strategy that you know (again by some magical means) will outperform the market, on average, by 5% per year over the next 25 years. The catch is that you also know that you will have a 5-year period where you underperform by 5% per year.

Which strategy do you choose? If you are a professional money manager, the choice is obvious: you choose A.

Why choose A? It a bad strategy relative to B.

It all boils down to tracking error and the incentives of the investment manager. Fund managers are not the owners of the capital, which creates a principal agent problem. These managers sometimes make decisions that ensure they maintain a job, but not necessarily maximize risk-adjusted returns for their investors. For these managers, tracking error is everything. The tracking error on strategy B is just too painful. Those firemen are going to start screaming bloody murder during years 3 and 4 of your underperformance, and you won’t be around long enough to see the rebound when it occurs after year 5. But if you follow strategy A, you can lock in a nice job for a long time.

Now it may be that, over long time frames, this arbitrage opportunity is a mile wide – you could drive a proverbial truck through it. But it is this agency problem – the fact that the owners of the capital can, in lean times, begin to doubt the abilities of the arbitrageur and pull their capital – that precludes the arbitrageurs from taking advantage of the opportunity.

It may be for this reason that an anomaly like value investing has continued to work, year after year, and decade after decade, ever since Ben Graham began talking about it almost 100 years ago. People simply cannot stay with it for the long haul, since periodic underperformance drives investors away from the strategy, which means that managers will avoid it, due to career risk. Hence, this could be a factor in why the anomaly can persist over time.

Putting it all together

We know that behavioral biases can drive stock market anomalies, such as Value and Momentum. And we also know that, due to limits to arbitrage, such anomalies can persist over time, which creates an opportunity for the investor. If an investor can identify situations where these two conditions hold, we may have an opportunity to exploit the bias, by investing in mispriced securities.

Now what is required is a systematic approach to taking advantage of situations that arise we can do so. As it turns out, there are many such approaches, and we invite our readers to follow us as we examine some of these critically on this blog.

Important Disclosures

For informational and educational purposes only and should not be construed as specific investment, accounting, legal, or tax advice. Certain information is deemed to be reliable, but its accuracy and completeness cannot be guaranteed. Third party information may become outdated or otherwise superseded without notice. Neither the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) nor any other federal or state agency has approved, determined the accuracy, or confirmed the adequacy of this article.

The views and opinions expressed herein are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the views of Alpha Architect, its affiliates or its employees. Our full disclosures are availablehere.Definitions of common statistics used in our analysis are availablehere(towards the bottom).

Join thousands of other readers andsubscribe to our blog.

Introduction to Behavioral Finance – Part 2: Limits of Arbitrage (2024)

FAQs

What are the limits to arbitrage in behavioral finance? ›

Limits to arbitrage is a theory in financial economics that, due to restrictions that are placed on funds that would ordinarily be used by rational traders to arbitrage away pricing inefficiencies, prices may remain in a non-equilibrium state for protracted periods of time.

What is the limits to arbitrage argument? ›

What is limits to arbitrage? Arbitrage means simultaneously buying and selling an asset to profit from a difference in its price. The theory of limits to arbitrage says that these prices may stay in an unbalanced state for a significant period of time due to restrictions on so-called rational traders.

What is arbitrage pdf? ›

Arbitrage is a financial strategy that simultaneously buys and sells financial instruments to profit from price discrepancies in different markets. For example, arbitrage in the credit derivatives market involves buying and selling credit default swaps (CDS) to benefit from price differences.

Why is arbitrage illegal? ›

Arbitrage trades are not illegal, but they are risky. Arbitrage is the act of taking advantage of a discrepancy between two almost identical financial instruments. These are typically traded on different financial markets or exchanges. It happens by buying and selling for a higher price somewhere else simultaneously.

What are the factors that limit arbitrage? ›

There exist three categories of risk that result in the limits of arbitrage: namely, fundamental risk, noise trader risk and implementation risk.

What are the two types of arbitrage? ›

Types of Arbitrage
  • Pure Arbitrage: The arbitrageur makes a buy or sells decision right away, without having to wait for funds to clear.
  • Retail Arbitrage: This is a popular e-commerce activity. ...
  • Risk Arbitrage: ...
  • Convertible Arbitrage: ...
  • Merger Arbitrage: ...
  • Dividend Arbitrage: ...
  • Futures Arbitrage:

What is the arbitrage formula? ›

The Arbitrage Pricing Theory is calculated by summing the asset's sensitivity coefficients to each macroeconomic factor, multiplying by the corresponding factor's return, and adding the risk-free rate and an error term.

What is arbitrage for dummies? ›

Arbitrage is a condition where you can simultaneously buy and sell the same or similar product or asset at different prices, resulting in a risk-free profit. Economic theory states that arbitrage should not be able to occur because if markets are efficient, there would be no such opportunities to profit.

What is arbitrage examples? ›

An example of arbitrage is when somebody buys a stock on one exchange for ten dollars and immediately sells it on another exchange for eleven dollars. The person has made a profit of one dollar without having to put any money at risk.

Is arbitrage good or bad? ›

Arbitrage, at its core, is important for narrowing the price differences between identical or similar assets — typically stocks, commodities and currencies. Arbitrage helps to make the financial markets more efficient by eliminating price differences. Investors can benefit from this by achieving low-risk yields.

Why arbitrage doesn't work? ›

In short, retail arbitrage is a cheap, low-risk, quick way for someone to get into selling. But, with the entire model relying on other retailers to provide products, retail arbitrage is limited in its growth potential. Nearly all of these limitations are tied to one core problem: you're at the mercy of retailers.

Is arbitrage legal in the USA? ›

Arbitrage trading is not only legal in the United States, but is encouraged, as it contributes to market efficiency. Furthermore, arbitrageurs also serve a useful purpose by acting as intermediaries, providing liquidity in different markets.

What are the limitations of arbitrage pricing? ›

The Cons: Disadvantages of Arbitrage Pricing Theory
  • Difficulty in identifying and measuring model factors,
  • Estimation problems stemming from the uncertain nature of the factors,
  • Lack of a testable market model, and.
  • Potential breach of the "no-arbitrage" condition in real-world scenarios.

What is the arbitrage model in behavioral finance? ›

Arbitrage pricing theory (APT) is a multi-factor asset pricing model based on the idea that an asset's returns can be predicted using the linear relationship between the asset's expected return and a number of macroeconomic variables that capture systematic risk.

Are good examples of the limits to arbitrage because they show that the law of one price is violated? ›

Siamese Twin Companies, closed end funds, and equity carve outs are good examples of the limits to arbitrage because they show that the law of one price is violated.

What are the conditions of arbitrage? ›

Arbitrage is a condition where you can simultaneously buy and sell the same or similar product or asset at different prices, resulting in a risk-free profit. Economic theory states that arbitrage should not be able to occur because if markets are efficient, there would be no such opportunities to profit.

References

Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Laurine Ryan

Last Updated:

Views: 6306

Rating: 4.7 / 5 (57 voted)

Reviews: 80% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Laurine Ryan

Birthday: 1994-12-23

Address: Suite 751 871 Lissette Throughway, West Kittie, NH 41603

Phone: +2366831109631

Job: Sales Producer

Hobby: Creative writing, Motor sports, Do it yourself, Skateboarding, Coffee roasting, Calligraphy, Stand-up comedy

Introduction: My name is Laurine Ryan, I am a adorable, fair, graceful, spotless, gorgeous, homely, cooperative person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.